RefBan

Referral Banners

Yashi

Wednesday, August 31, 2011

Today's Business & Economics Chapter

 
BookDaily
BookDaily.com My Sample Shelf
(0) Books remaining on Shelf
Business & Investing
Thursday September 1, 2011
Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist's Companion
by Joshua D. Angrist
 

Questions about Questions

"I checked it very thoroughly," said the computer, "and that quite definitely is the answer. I think the problem, to be quite honest with you, is that you've never actually known what the question is." Douglas Adams, The Hitchhiker's Guide to the Galaxy

This chapter briefly discusses the basis for a successful research project. Like the biblical story of Exodus, a research agenda can be organized around four questions. We call these frequently asked questions (FAQs), because they should be. The FAQs ask about the relationship of interest, the ideal experiment, the identification strategy, and the mode of inference.

In the beginning, we should ask, What is the causal relationship of interest? Although purely descriptive research has an important role to play, we believe that the most interesting research in social science is about questions of cause and effect, such as the effect of class size on children's test scores, discussed in chapters 2 and 6. A causal relationship is useful for making predictions about the consequences of changing circumstances or policies; it tells us what would happen in alternative (or "counterfactual") worlds. For example, as part of a research agenda investigating human productive capacity-what labor economists call human capital-we have both investigated the causal effect of schooling on wages (Card, 1999, surveys research in this area). The causal effect of schooling on wages is the increment to wages an individual would receive if he or she got more schooling. A range of studies suggest the causal effect of a college degree is about 40 percent higher wages on average, quite a payoff. The causal effect of schooling on wages is useful for predicting the earnings consequences of, say, changing the costs of attending college, or strengthening compulsory attendance laws. This relation is also of theoretical interest since it can be derived from an economic model.

As labor economists, we're most likely to study causal effects in samples of workers, but the unit of observation in causal research need not be an individual human being. Causal questions can be asked about firms or, for that matter, countries. Take, for example, Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson's (2001) research on the effect of colonial institutions on economic growth. This study is concerned with whether countries that inherited more democratic institutions from their colonial rulers later enjoyed higher economic growth as a consequence. The answer to this question has implications for our understanding of history and for the consequences of contemporary development policy. Today, we might wonder whether newly forming democratic institutions are important for economic development in Iraq and Afghanistan. The case for democracy is far from clear-cut; at the moment, China is enjoying robust economic growth without the benefit of complete political freedom, while much of Latin America has democratized without a big growth payoff.

The second research FAQ is concerned with the experiment that could ideally be used to capture the causal effect of interest. In the case of schooling and wages, for example, we can imagine offering potential dropouts a reward for finishing school, and then studying the consequences. In fact, Angrist and Lavy (2008) have run just such an experiment. Although their study looked at short-term effects such as college enrollment, a longer-term follow-up might well look at wages. In the case of political institutions, we might like to go back in time and randomly assign different government structures in former colonies on their independence day (an experiment that is more likely to be made into a movie than to get funded by the National Science Foundation).

Ideal experiments are most often hypothetical. Still, hypothetical experiments are worth contemplating because they help us pick fruitful research topics. We'll support this claim by asking you to picture yourself as a researcher with no budget constraint and no Human Subjects Committee policing your inquiry for social correctness: something like a well-funded Stanley Milgram, the psychologist who did pathbreaking work on the response to authority in the 1960s using highly controversial experimental designs that would likely cost him his job today.

Seeking to understand the response to authority, Milgram (1963) showed he could convince experimental subjects to administer painful electric shocks to pitifully protesting victims (the shocks were fake and the victims were actors). This turned out to be controversial as well as clever: some psychologists claimed that the subjects who administered shocks were psychologically harmed by the experiment. Still, Milgram's study illustrates the point that there are many experiments we can think about, even if some are better left on the drawing board. If you can't devise an experiment that answers your question in a world where anything goes, then the odds of generating useful results with a modest budget and nonexperimental survey data seem pretty slim. The description of an ideal experiment also helps you formulate causal questions precisely. The mechanics of an ideal experiment highlight the forces you'd like to manipulate and the factors you'd like to hold constant.

Research questions that cannot be answered by any experiment are FUQs: fundamentally unidentified questions. What exactly does a FUQ look like? At first blush, questions about the causal effect of race or gender seem good candidates because these things are hard to manipulate in isolation ("imagine your chromosomes were switched at birth"). On the other hand, the issue economists care most about in the realm of race and sex, labor market discrimination, turns on whether someone treats you differently because they believe you to be black or white, male or female. The notion of a counterfactual world where men are perceived as women or vice versa has a long history and does not require Douglas Adams-style outlandishness to entertain (Rosalind disguised as Ganymede fools everyone in Shakespeare's As You Like It). The idea of changing race is similarly near-fetched: in The Human Stain, Philip Roth imagines the world of Coleman Silk, a black literature professor who passes as white in professional life. Labor economists imagine this sort of thing all the time. Sometimes we even construct such scenarios for the advancement of science, as in audit studies involving fake job applicants and resumes.

A little imagination goes a long way when it comes to research design, but imagination cannot solve every problem. Suppose that we are interested in whether children do better in school by virtue of having started school a little older. Maybe the 7-year-old brain is better prepared for learning than the 6-year-old brain. This question has a policy angle coming from the fact that, in an effort to boost test scores, some school districts are now imposing older start ages (Deming and Dynarski, 2008). To assess the effects of delayed school entry on learning, we could randomly select some kids to start first grade at age 7, while others start at age 6, as is still typical. We are interested in whether those held back learn more in school, as evidenced by their elementary school test scores. To be concrete, let's look at test scores in first grade.

The problem with this question-the effects of start age on first grade test scores-is that the group that started school at age 7 is ... older. And older kids tend to do better on tests, a pure maturation effect. Now, it might seem we can fix this by holding age constant instead of grade. Suppose we wait to test those who started at age 6 until second grade and test those who started at age 7 in first grade, so that everybody is tested at age 7. But the first group has spent more time in school, a fact that raises achievement if school is worth anything. There is no way to disentangle the effect of start age on learning from maturation and time-in-school effects as long as kids are still in school. The problem here is that for students, start age equals current age minus time in school. This deterministic link disappears in a sample of adults, so we can investigate pure start-age effects on adult outcomes, such as earnings or highest grade completed (as in Black, Devereux, and Salvanes, 2008). But the effect of start age on elementary school test scores is impossible to interpret even in a randomized trial, and therefore, in a word, FUQed.

The third and fourth research FAQs are concerned with the nuts-and-bolts elements that produce a specific study. Question number 3 asks, What is your identification strategy? Angrist and Krueger (1999) used the term identification strategy to describe the manner in which a researcher uses observational data (i.e., data not generated by a randomized trial) to approximate a real experiment. Returning to the schooling example, Angrist and Krueger (1991) used the interaction between compulsory attendance laws in American states and students' season of birth as a natural experiment to estimate the causal effects of finishing high school on wages (season of birth affects the degree to which high school students are constrained by laws allowing them to drop out after their 16th birthday). Chapters 3-6 are primarily concerned with conceptual frameworks for identification strategies.

Although a focus on credible identification strategies is emblematic of modern empirical work, the juxtaposition of ideal and natural experiments has a long history in econometrics. Here is our econometrics forefather, Trygve Haavelmo (1944, p. 14), appealing for more explicit discussion of both kinds of experimental designs:

A design of experiments (a prescription of what the physicists call a "crucial experiment") is an essential appendix to any quantitative theory. And we usually have some such experiment in mind when we construct the theories, although-unfortunately-most economists do not describe their design of experiments explicitly. If they did, they would see that the experiments they have in mind may be grouped into two different classes, namely, (1) experiments that we should like to make to see if certain real economic phenomena-when artificially isolated from "other influences"-would verify certain hypotheses, and (2) the stream of experiments that Nature is steadily turning out from her own enormous laboratory, and which we merely watch as passive observers. In both cases the aim of the theory is the same, to become master of the happenings of real life.

The fourth research FAQ borrows language from Rubin (1991): What is your mode of statistical inference? The answer to this question describes the population to be studied, the sample to be used, and the assumptions made when constructing standard errors. Sometimes inference is straightforward, as when you use census microdata samples to study the American population. Often inference is more complex, however, especially with data that are clustered or grouped. The last chapter covers practical problems that arise once you've answered question number 4. Although inference issues are rarely very exciting, and often quite technical, the ultimate success of even a well-conceived and conceptually exciting project turns on the details of statistical inference. This sometimes dispiriting fact inspired the following econometrics haiku, penned by Keisuke Hirano after completing his thesis:

T-stat looks too good Try clustered standard errors- Significance gone

As should be clear from the above discussion, the four research FAQs are part of a process of project development. The following chapters are concerned mostly with the econometric questions that come up after you've answered the research FAQs-in other words, issues that arise once your research agenda has been set. Before turning to the nuts and bolts of empirical work, however, we begin with a more detailed explanation of why randomized trials give us our benchmark.

Chapter Two

The Experimental Ideal

It is an important and popular fact that things are not always what they seem. For instance, on the planet Earth, man had always assumed that he was more intelligent than dolphins because he had achieved so much-the wheel, New York, wars and so on-while all the dolphins had ever done was muck about in the water having a good time. But conversely, the dolphins had always believed that they were far more intelligent than man-for precisely the same reasons. In fact there was only one species on the planet more intelligent than dolphins, and they spent a lot of their time in behavioral research laboratories running round inside wheels and conducting frighteningly elegant and subtle experiments on man. The fact that once again man completely misinterpreted this relationship was entirely according to these creatures' plans. Douglas Adams, The Hitchhiker's Guide to the Galaxy

The most credible and influential research designs use random assignment. A case in point is the Perry preschool project, a 1962 randomized experiment designed to assess the effects of an early intervention program involving 123 black preschoolers in Ypsilanti, Michigan. The Perry treatment group was randomly assigned to an intensive intervention that included preschool education and home visits. It's hard to exaggerate the impact of the small but well-designed Perry experiment, which generated follow-up data through 1993 on the participants at age 27. Dozens of academic studies cite or use the Perry findings (see, e.g., Barnett, 1992). Most important, the Perry project provided the intellectual basis for the massive Head Start preschool program, begun in 1964, which ultimately served (and continues to serve) millions of American children.

2.1 The Selection Problem

We take a brief time-out for a more formal discussion of the role experiments play in uncovering causal effects. Suppose you are interested in a causal if-then question. To be concrete, let us consider a simple example: Do hospitals make people healthier? For our purposes, this question is allegorical, but it is surprisingly close to the sort of causal question health economists care about. To make this question more realistic, let's imagine we're studying a poor elderly population that uses hospital emergency rooms for primary care. Some of these patients are admitted to the hospital. This sort of care is expensive, crowds hospital facilities, and is, perhaps, not very effective (see, e.g., Grumbach, Keane, and Bindman, 1993). In fact, exposure to other sick patients by those who are themselves vulnerable might have a net negative impact on their health.

Since those admitted to the hospital get many valuable services, the answer to the hospital effectiveness question still seems likely to be yes. But will the data back this up? The natural approach for an empirically minded person is to compare the health status of those who have been to the hospital with the health of those who have not. The National Health Interview Survey (NHIS) contains the information needed to make this comparison. Specifically, it includes a question, "During the past 12 months, was the respondent a patient in a hospital overnight?" which we can use to identify recent hospital visitors. The NHIS also asks, "Would you say your health in general is excellent, very good, good, fair, poor?"

The following table displays the mean health status (assigning a 1 to poor health and a 5 to excellent health) among those who have been hospitalized and those who have not (tabulated from the 2005 NHIS):

Group Sample Size Mean Health Status Std. Error

Hospital 7,774 3.21 0.014 No hospital 90,049 3.93 0.003

The difference in means is 0.72, a large and highly significant contrast in favor of the nonhospitalized, with a t-statistic of 58.9.

(Continues...)

 
 
 
 
 
BookDaily Top Five
  1. Heaven is for Real: A Little Boy's Astounding Story of ...
  2. A Dance with Dragons: A Song of Ice and Fire: Book Five
  3. The Great Gatsby
  4. In the Garden of Beasts: Love, Terror, and an American ...
  5. Things Fall Apart
 
 
Business & Investing Top Five
  1. The 7 Habits of Highly Effective People
  2. Who Moved My Cheese?: An Amazing Way to Deal with Change ...
  3. Nickel and Dimed: On (Not) Getting By in America
  4. Fast Food Nation: The Dark Side of the All-American Meal
  5. The Intelligent Investor: The Definitive Book on Value ...
 

Manage Your Subscriptions

You are currently subscribed as dwyld.kwu.careers@blogger.com.
To unsubscribe from this newsletter, please notify us here.

BookDaily, ArcaMax Publishing, Inc., 729 Thimble Shoals Blvd., Suite 1-B, Newport News, VA 23606 | FAX (757) 596-9731
Copyright © 2010 ArcaMax Publishing, Inc. All Rights Reserved.

Contact Us | FAQ/Help | Privacy Notice

 
 

BookDaily Update

 
BookDaily
BookDaily.com My Sample Shelf
(0) Books remaining on Shelf
BookDaily Update
Thursday September 1, 2011

Lot's Return to Sodom: A Liv Bergen Mystery (Liv Bergen Mysteries)

By Sandra Brannan
ISBN: 9781608321193
 

“Can you stay?” he asked her.

“Jens is picking me up at eight,” Michelle explained.

“Forget about him. I’ll give you a ride home,” Roy offered.

“I’m tired,” she protested, tilting her head from side to side to stretch her weary neck and shoulders. “Not that I don’t appreciate what you’re doing for me, Roy, letting me work extra hours so I can afford to pay off the last of my college loans, and I only have—”

“Two weeks left before graduation,” he interrupted. “I know, I know. You’ve always wanted to be a doctor and you’re one step closer. It’s great that you’re following your dream.”

“My ...

Read more
 
 

Between Two Worlds: The Legend Of Quanah Parker

By Cynthia Kay Rhodes
ISBN: 9781608602278
 

THE SECOND BATTLE OF THE ADOBE WALLS

“Two years ago, I came upon this road following the buffalo, that my wives and children might have their cheeks plump and their bodies warm. But the soldiers fired on us, and since that time there has been a noise like that of a thunderstorm, and we have not known which way to go.”17 Before boundaries were drawn and states were born, there lived a warrior named Quanah Parker. He roamed the open plains as a young man, saw the plains close, and fought the courts of Washington for his people’s rights. Quanah Parker was a man who stood at the crossroads of two worlds, one Comanche and the other Anglo.

Comancheria, the land of ...

Read more
 
 
 
 
BookDaily Top Five
  1. Heaven is for Real: A Little Boy's Astounding Story of ...
  2. A Dance with Dragons: A Song of Ice and Fire: Book Five
  3. Eat to Live: The Amazing Nutrient-Rich Program for Fast ...
  4. The Great Gatsby
  5. In the Garden of Beasts: Love, Terror, and an American ...
 
Browse by Category
Fiction
Romance
Mystery & Detective
Westerns
Sci-fi/ Fantasy
Thrillers
Political
Religion
Classics
Historical
Action & Adventure
Humorous
Children
Non-Fiction
Biography
Travel
Religion
Political
History
Social Issues
Business
Arts
Science
True Crime
Sports
Poetry
 

Manage Your Subscriptions

You are currently subscribed as dwyld.kwu.careers@blogger.com.
To unsubscribe from this newsletter, please notify us here.

BookDaily, ArcaMax Publishing, Inc., 729 Thimble Shoals Blvd., Suite 1-B, Newport News, VA 23606 | FAX (757) 596-9731
Copyright © 2010 ArcaMax Publishing, Inc. All Rights Reserved.

Contact Us | FAQ/Help | Privacy Notice

 
 

The New "Dancing With The Stars" Cast List Is Out, And Nancy Grace And Chaz Bono Are On It


View this email online | Add newsletter@businessinsider.com to your address book
The Wire Select Share this Email
Tech Entertainment Wall Street Markets Strategy Sports Lifestyle Politics Europe Video Latest

August 31, 2011
Find Us on FacebookFollow US on Twitter
The New The New "Dancing With The Stars" Cast List Is Out, And Nancy Grace And Chaz Bono Are On It

And so is Hope Solo.

 Read »

9 Celebrity Pregnancies Affecting Business In Hollywood Right Now 9 Celebrity Pregnancies Affecting Business In Hollywood Right Now
Beyonce is the least of it.  Read »
Mayor Bloomberg Rode The 4 Train To Work This Morning Mayor Bloomberg Rode The 4 Train To Work This Morning
And reading a lot of newspapers.  Read »
Check Out Heiress Petra Ecclestone's Over-The-Top Wedding (Seriously, Four A-List Singers Were There) Check Out Heiress Petra Ecclestone's Over-The-Top Wedding (Seriously, Four A-List Singers Were There)
Was the Kardashian wedding just a little too modest for you?  Read »
Al Sharpton Yelled His Way Through His Official MSNBC Premiere Last Night
"Nor am I going to come in here and do the James Brown."  Read »
Hannity: Obama Is The Dumb One
"If he's such a genius he would have not lost two and a half million jobs."  Read »
Advertisement

Here Is The Trailer For Johnny Depp's New Hunter S. Thompson Movie Here Is The Trailer For Johnny Depp's New Hunter S. Thompson Movie
The rum diary.  Read »
This Step-By-Step Guide Will Show You How To Hack Like A 'News Of The World' Reporter This Step-By-Step Guide Will Show You How To Hack Like A 'News Of The World' Reporter
Thanks Reuters!  Read »
Share this: Facebook Facebook Twitter Twitter Digg Digg Reddit Reddit StumbleUpon StumbleUpon LinkedIn LinkedIn
Find Us on Facebook Follow US on Twitter
The email address for your subscription is: dwyld.kwu.careers@blogger.com

Manage Email Preference | Unsubscribe | Subscribe | Subscribe to The Wire RSS Feed

Business Insider. 257 Park Avenue South, New York, NY 10010

Terms of Service | Privacy Policy


Yashi

Chitika